Citation: | S. Gao, J. Suo, and N. Li, “Cooperation under stochastic punishment in social dilemma situations,” IEEE/CAA J. Autom. Sinica, vol. 12, no. 5, pp. 1–3, May 2025. |
[1] |
J. J. M. Massen, “Studying the evolution of cooperation and prosociality in birds,” Ethology, vol. 126, pp. 121–124, Jan. 2020. doi: 10.1111/eth.13001
|
[2] |
J. Wang, Y. Hong, J. Wang, et al., “Cooperative and competitive multi-agent aystems: From optimization to games,” IEEE/CAA J. Autom. Sinica, vol. 9, no. 5, pp. 763–783, May 2022. doi: 10.1109/JAS.2022.105506
|
[3] |
D. G. Rand and M. A. Nowak, “Human cooperation,” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, vol. 17, no. 8, pp. 413–425, Aug. 2013. doi: 10.1016/j.tics.2013.06.003
|
[4] |
A. Romano, M. Sutter, and J. H. Liu, “National parochialism is ubiquitous across 42 nations around the world,” Nature Communications, vol. 12, p. 4456, Jul. 2021.
|
[5] |
W. Chen and T. Wu, “Adaptive multilayer networks resolve the cooperation dilemma induced by breaking the symmetry between interaction and learning,” New J. Physics, vol. 23, no. 9, p. 093019, Aug. 2021.
|
[6] |
C. Hilbe, Š. Šimsa, K. Chatterjee, et al., “Evolution of cooperation in stochastic games,” Nature, vol. 559, pp. 246–249, Jun. 2018. doi: 10.1038/s41586-018-0277-x
|
[7] |
H. Ohtsuki, C. Hauert, E. Lieberman, et al., “A simple rule for the evolution of cooperation on graphs and social networks,” Nature, vol. 441, pp. 502–505, Jan. 2006. doi: 10.1038/nature04605
|
[8] |
X. Lei, C. Sun, D. Wunsch, et al., “An adaptive strategy via reinforcement learning for the prisoner’s dilemma game,” IEEE/CAA J. Autom. Sinica, vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 301–3130, Jan. 2018. doi: 10.1109/JAS.2017.7510466
|
[9] |
M. A. Nowak, “Five rules for the evolution of cooperation,” Science, vol. 314, pp. 1560–1563, Dec. 2006. doi: 10.1126/science.1133755
|
[10] |
K. Li, R. Cong, T. Wu, and L. Wang, “Social exclusion in finite populations,” Physical Review E, vol. 91, p. 42810, Mar. 2015.
|
[11] |
L. Liu, X. Chen, and M. Perc, “Evolutionary dynamics of cooperation in the public goods game with pool exclusion strategies,” Nonlinear Dynamics, vol. 97, pp. 749–766, Jun. 2019. doi: 10.1007/s11071-019-05010-9
|
[12] |
A. Szolnoki and M. Perc. “Second-order free-riding on antisocial punishment restores the effectiveness of prosocial punishment,” Physical Review X, vol. 7, no. 4, p. 041027, Oct. 2017.
|
[13] |
S. Wang, L. Liu, and X. Chen, “Tax-based pure punishment and reward in the public goods game,” Physics Letters A, vol. 386, p. 126965, Jan. 2021.
|
[14] |
C. Hauert, A. Traulsen, H. Brandt, et al., “Via freedom to coercion: The emergence of costly punishment,” Science, vol. 316, pp. 1905–1907, Jul. 2007. doi: 10.1126/science.1141588
|
[15] |
D. G. Rand, J. J. Armao IV, M. Nakamaru, and H. Ohtsuki, “Anti-social punishment can prevent the co-evolution of punishment and cooperation,” J. Theoretical Biology, vol. 265, pp. 624–632, Aug. 2010. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2010.06.010
|
[16] |
O. P. Hauser, M. A. Nowak, and D. G. Rand, “Punishment does not promote cooperation under exploration dynamics when anti-social punishment is possible,” J. Theoretical Biology, vol. 360, pp. 163–171, Jul. 2014. doi: 10.1016/j.jtbi.2014.06.041
|
[17] |
K. Sigmund, H. De Silva, A. Traulsen, and C. Hauert, “Social learning promotes institutions for governing the commons,” Nature, vol. 466, pp. 861–863, Jul. 2010. doi: 10.1038/nature09203
|